網頁圖片
PDF
ePub 版

Figure 1: Population Aged 65 and Older, by Age Group, 1940-2050

[merged small][graphic][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Note: Data for 2000 to 2050 are midrange Bureau of the Census projections. Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, 65+ in the United States (Washington, DC: U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1996).

Although the baby-boom generation will greatly contribute to the growth of the elderly population, other demographic trends are also important. Life expectancy has increased continually since the 1930's, and further improvements are expected. In 1940, 65-year-old men could expect to live another 12 years, and women could expect to live another 13 years. By 1995, these numbers had improved to 15 years for men and 19 for women. By 2040, these numbers are projected to be 17 years and 21 years, according to SSA's intermediate actuarial assumptions. Note that these assumptions yield a lower rate of elderly population growth than do the Census assumptions. Some demographers project even more dramatic growth.

A falling fertility rate is the other principal factor in the growth of the elderly's share of the population. The fertility rate was 3.6 children per woman in 1960. The rate has declined to around 2.0 children per woman today and is expected to level off at about 1.9 by 2020, according to SSA's intermediate assumptions.

Increasing life expectancy and falling fertility rates in combination mean that fewer workers will be contributing to Social Security for each aged, disabled, dependent, or surviving beneficiary. There were 3.3 workers for each Social Security beneficiary in 1995, but by 2030, only 2.0 workers are projected for each beneficiary (see fig. 2).

Figure 2: Workers Contributing to Social Security per Beneficiary, Historical and Projected, 1960-2040

[ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Note: Projections use SSA's intermediate actuarial assumptions.

Source: Board of Trustees, 1997 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old Age and Survivors Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (Washington, DC: SSA, 1997).

These demographic trends have fundamental implications for Social Security, other forms of retirement income, and our economy as a whole. Increasing longevity means that each year more people will receive Social Security benefits. As a result, Social Security revenues must be increased, benefits must be reduced, or both. For pensions and retirement savings, increasing longevity means these income sources will have to provide income over longer periods, which will similarly require increased contributions or reduced retirement income. As already noted, there will be relatively fewer workers to pay the Social Security taxes needed to fund benefits. However, more fundamentally, unless retirement patterns change, there will be relatively fewer workers producing the goods and services that both workers' households and elderly households will consume. Yet in recent years, workers have been retiring earlier, not later, and not always by choice.

These demographic trends also pose challenges for our long-term budget outlook. They will lead to higher costs in medicare and medicaid as well as in Social Security. In a recent report to the Chairmen of the Senate and House Budget Committees,2 we discussed the results of our latest simulations of the long-term budget outlook. Recent congressional action to bring about a balanced budget and surplus in the next 10 years will give us some breathing room, but spending pressures in these programs, if left unchecked, will prompt the emergence of unsustainable deficits over the longer term.

HOW SOCIAL SECURITY'S PROBLEM WILL DEVELOP OVER TIME

These demographic trends pose long-term financing challenges for both Social Security and the Federal budget. Social Security revenues are expected to be about 14 percent less than expenditures over the next 75 years, and demographic trends suggest that this imbalance will grow over time. In 2029, the Social Security Trust Funds are projected to be depleted. From then on, Social Security revenues are expected to be sufficient to pay only about 70 to 75 percent of currently promised benefits, given currently scheduled tax rates and SSA's intermediate assumptions about demographic and economic trends. In 2031, the last members of the baby-boom generation will reach age 67, when they will be eligible for full retirement benefits under current law.

2 See Budget Issues: Analysis of Long-Term Fiscal Outlook (GAO/AIMD/OCE-98–19, Oct. 22,

While Social Security funds are expected to be sufficient to pay full benefits for more than 30 years, Social Security's financing will begin having significant implications for the Federal budget in only 10 years. Moreover, restoring Social Security's long-range financial balance would not necessarily address the significant challenge that its current financing arrangements pose for the overall Federal budget. Social Security cash revenues currently exceed expenditures by roughly $30 billion each year (see fig. 3). Under current law, the Department of the Treasury issues interestbearing Government securities to the trust funds for these excess revenues. In effect, Treasury borrows Social Security's excess revenues and uses them to help reduce the amount it must borrow from the public. In other words, Social Security's excess revenues help reduce the overall, or unified, Federal budget deficit. Moreover, the trust funds earned $38 billion in interest last year, which Treasury pays by issuing more securities. If Treasury could not borrow from the trust funds, it would have to borrow more in the private capital market and pay such interest in cash to finance current budget policy.

Figure 3: Social Security's Cash Revenues Exceed Expenditures Now but Fall Short Later

[ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Sources: 1997 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old Age and Survivors Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds and unpublished SSA data.

Ten years from now, these excess cash revenues are expected to start diminishing, and so will their effect in helping balance the budget. In just 15 years, Social Security's expenditures are expected to exceed its cash revenues, and the Government's general fund will have to make up the difference, in effect repaying Social Security. As a result, Social Security's cash flow will no longer help efforts to balance the budget but will start to hinder them. In 2028, repayments from the general fund to Social Security are expected to reach about $183 billion in 1997 dollars. In that year, this amount would equal the same share of gross domestic product as the deficit for the entire Federal Government in fiscal year 1996, or 1.4 percent, according to SSA projections.

ALTERNATIVES FOR REFORM

Restoring Social Security's long-term financial balance will require some combination of increased revenues and reduced expenditures. A variety of options is available within the current structure of the program. However, some proposals would go beyond restoring financial balance and fundamentally alter the program structure. These more dramatic changes attempt to achieve other policy objectives as well.

The current Social Security System attempts to balance two competing policy objectives. The progressive benefit formula tries to ensure the "adequacy" of retirement income by replacing a higher portion of lower earners' income than of higher earners' income. In effect, Social Security redistributes income from higher earners to lower earners. At the same time, the formula attempts to maintain some degree of "equity" for higher earners by providing that benefits increase somewhat with earnings.

Within the current program structure, a wide range of options is available for reducing costs or increasing revenues. Previously enacted reforms have used many of these in some form. Current reform proposals also rely, at least in part, on many of these more traditional measures, regardless of whether the proposals largely preserve the current program structure or alter it significantly. Ways to reduce program expenditures include:

• reducing initial benefits by changing the benefit formula for all or some beneficiaries, for example, by changing the number of years of earnings used in the formula;

• raising the retirement age or accelerating the currently scheduled increase;

• lowering the annual automatic cost-of-living adjustment; and

• means-testing benefits, or limiting benefits on the basis of beneficiaries' other income and assets.

Ways to increase revenues include:

• increasing Social Security payroll taxes,

⚫ investing trust funds in securities with potentially higher yields than the Government bonds in which they are currently invested, and

• increasing income taxes on Social Security benefits.

A variety of proposals would address Social Security's long-term funding problems by significantly restructuring the program, usually by privatizing at least a portion of it. Such proposals still essentially achieve financial balance by effectively raising revenues and reducing costs, but they do so in ways that pursue other policy objectives as well. Some of these proposals would reduce the role of Social Security and the Federal Government in providing retirement income and would give individuals greater responsibility and control over their own retirement incomes. These proposals often focus on trying to improve the rates of return that individuals earn on their retirement contributions and thus place greater emphasis on the equity objective. Also, some proposals focus on trying to increase national saving and on funding future Social Security benefits in advance rather than on the current pay-as-yougo basis. In this way, the relatively larger generation of current workers could finance some of their future benefits now rather than leaving a relatively smaller generation of workers with the entire financing responsibility. Moreover, the investment earnings on the saved funds would reduce the total payroll tax burden.

Generally, privatization proposals focus on setting up individual retirement savings accounts and requiring workers to contribute to them. The accounts would usually replace a portion of Social Security, whose benefits would be reduced to compensate for revenues diverted to the savings accounts. Some privatization proposals combine new mandatory saving and Social Security benefit cuts, hoping to produce a potential net gain in retirement income. The combination of mandated savings deposits and revised Social Security taxes would be greater than current Social Security taxes, in most cases.

Virtually all proposals addressing long-term financing issues would increase the proportion of retirement assets invested in the stock market or in other higher-risk investments. Some proposals call for the accounts to be managed by individuals, while others would have them managed by the government. The common objective is to finance a smaller share of retirement costs with worker contributions and a larger share of the costs with anticipated higher investment returns.

In the case of individual savings accounts, workers would bear the risk of economic and market performance. Individuals with identical earning histories and retirement contributions could have notably dfferent retirement incomes because of market fluctuations or individual investment choices. Some proposals would require retirees to purchase a lifetime annuity with their retirement savings to ensure that the savings provided income throughout their retirement.

Privatization proposals raise the issue of how to make the transition to a new system. Social Security would still need revenues to pay benefits that retirees and current workers have already earned, yet financing retirement through individually owned savings accounts requires advance funding. The revenues needed to fund both current and future liabilities would clearly be higher than those currently col

lected. For example, to fund the transition, one proposal would increase payroll taxes by 1.52 percent for 72 years and involve borrowing $2 trillion during the first 40 years of the transition.

Privatization would also have a signiftcant effect on the distribution of retirement income between high and low earners. The current Social Security benefit formula redistributes income and implicitly gives low earners a somewhat higher rate of return on their contributions than high earners. Privatization proponents claim that all earners would be better off under privatization, although high earners would have relatively more to gain from any increased rates of return that privatization might provide. Moreover, if workers were contributing to their own retirement savings, their contributions would not be available for redistribution as they are now. Some privatization proposals would retain some degree of Social Security coverage and therefore permit some redistribution to continue.

Privatization proposals also tend to separate retirement benefits from Social Security's survivors' and disability benefits. In the case of death or disability before retirement, individual savings may not have been building long enough to sufficiently replace lost income. Some privatization proposals, therefore, leave these social insurance programs largely as they are now.

IMPLICATIONS OF REFORM

Financing reforms could affect the Nation's economy in various ways. For example, raising the retirement age could affect the labor market for elderly workers. Also, if reforms increased national saving, they could help increase investment, which in turn could increase productivity and economic growth. Economic growth could help ease the strains of providing for a growing elderly population. However, reforms may not produce notable increases in national saving since, to some degree, any new retirement saving might simply replace other forms of individual saving, Moreover, any additional Social Security savings in the Federal budget would add to national saving only if they were not offset by other budget initiatives.

Reforms would affect other sources of retirement income and related public policies as well. For example, raising payroll taxes could affect the ability of workers to save for retirement, especially if these increases were combined with tax increases enacted to help with medicare or medicaid financing. Raising Social Security's retirement age or cutting its benefit amounts could increase costs for private pensions that adjust benefits in relation to Social Security benefits. Reforms would also interact with other income support programs, such as Social Security's Disability Insurance Program or the Supplemental Security Income Public Assistance Pro

gram.

Reforms could have effects both immediately and far into the future. For example, bringing newly hired State and local government workers into the Social Security System would immediately increase revenues but would increase benefit payments only when the newly covered workers retired. However, even changes that take effect years from now can affect how workers plan now for their retirement, especially how much they choose to save. Therefore, the sooner solutions are enacted, the more time workers will have to adjust their retirement planning. Acting sooner rather than later also would mean that the funding shortfall could be addressed over a longer period at a lower annual cost.

Finally, any financing reforms would implicitly have distributional effects. For example, increasing Social Security taxes would reduce the disposable income of current workers but would help sustain retirement benefits for retirees in the future. Cutting benefits instead of increasing payroll taxes would have the opposite distributional effect. Also, Social Security redistributes income from high to low earners to some degree; some reforms would change this. In particular, reform proposals vary considerably in their effects on specific subpopulations, some of which are at greater risk of poverty, such as older women and unmarried women. For example, since men and women have different earnings histories, life expectancies, and investment behaviors, reforms could exacerbate dfferences in benefits that already exist.

OBSERVATIONS

Ensuring that Americans have adequate retirement income in the 21st century will require that the Nation and the Congress make some difficult choices. Social Security has been effective in ensuring a reliable source of income in retirement and greatly reducing poverty among the elderly, and reforms will determine what role it will play in the future. The effect of reforms on other retirement income sources and on various groups within the aged population should be well understood when making reforms.

« 上一頁繼續 »